The return of "the Big State" will be short-lived
English original of column published this week in Japanese by Nikkei Business. Industrial policy is fashionable -- but the realities of public debt make it unlikely to last
Economists usually find plenty of ways to disagree about the true meaning of government economic policies. The big innovation of the past 10-15 years was monetary, with the Bank of Japan at the forefront of what became a worldwide practice of money-creation and the mass-purchase of government securities by central banks. Economists debated the ultimate purpose of this policy trend – was it anti-deflation, or aimed at rescuing banks and securities markets, or financing public investment? – but the trend itself was indisputable.
Now the big trend is that of industrial policy, with vast programmes of public subsidies and investment, but strangely there is much less debate about it. President Joe Biden has led the way in the United States, which is why some call it “Bidenomics”, although the European Union actually got there first with its “Next Generation EU” fund that was set up during the COVID pandemic. But America sees its programme as bigger, better and more headline-grabbing, which is why the tempting slogan of “Bidenomics” has taken hold, following the earlier examples of Reaganomics and Abenomics.
What economists seem to agree on is that these big programmes mean that they call the Big State is back. This is epitomised in the United States by the Chips and Science Act, devoting $52.7 billion to supporting the semiconductor industry, and the Inflation Reduction Act, under which more than $400 billion is being spent over the next 10 years on the energy transition and on infrastructure.
By “the Big State” is meant large-scale state intervention in industry, which also means favouring national producers at the expense of imported goods and services, which makes this policy trend also protectionist.
That protectionist aspect contributes to a widespread feeling that the era of globalisation might be over. With America and the EU leading the way with big-spending industrial and infrastructure policies, it is assumed that other countries such as Japan and the United Kingdom will have to try to compete so as to stop their own firms and own production moving to where the biggest subsidies are on offer.
Thanks to that theory of competition between nations, the consensus among economists seems to be that this trend of big-spending industrial policies is here to stay: that just as the big monetary policy trend lasted more than a decade, so will this one.
In support of that argument are two other factors: first, the fact that the battle against climate change and for the green energy transition is a long-term one which will require public subsidies and investment if it is to succeed; and second, that the technological and military contest between the US and China is also a long-term reality that will perpetuate big-spending industrial policies designed to prevent Chinese dominance, whether military or economic.
To me, however, the idea of this as a long-term trend is both compelling and lacking in credibility. It is compelling because it is true that geopolitical competition and tensions, and the urgency of dealing with climate change, both feel like they are fundamental to our era. But it is lacking in credibility for a simpler reason: public subsidies and investment need somehow to be financed, and financing these ambitious industrial policies will be very difficult at a time of high levels of sovereign debt and rising interest rates.
The paradox of the previous, monetary-policy-dominated era was that when borrowing was ultra-cheap, few governments felt able to exploit it to finance big programmes of public investment. Now that borrowing costs are rising, governments are nonetheless trying to finance costly programmes of public investment.
Doing so would be sustainable only if those programmes were to succeed in raising the long-term rate of economic growth and thus in raising tax revenues. It would be wonderful if they did have that long-term growth-boosting effect. But it is more likely that any positive effect on growth will be quite short-lived, as it is competing with the negative effects of rising borrowing costs.
The era of big-state industrial policy feels to me as if it will actually prove quite short-lived, at least as a broad phenomenon. For example, political battles in the United States about the official ceiling on federal public debt make it hard to envisage that the Inflation Reduction Act could ever be repeated.
The smaller, geopolitical element to this industrial policy trend might well persist, since both technological export-controls and so-called “de-risking” from dependence on China are driven by politics and not economics. The larger, climate-related portion will also persist in some form, but electorates are always reluctant to vote for tax rises to pay for it. Overall, the wider popularity of industrial policy runs up against the realities of high public debt. Now that it has been noticed and, by some at least, celebrated, the phenomenon is probably already peaking.
Thank you, Bill, for this insight. As I was reading two thoughts came to my mind. The first was how will the war in Ukraine affect Big State projects. The second was the randomness of concentric leadership. What I mean is that when great leadership by chance occurs simultaneously in concert at multiple and different economic poles, investment will take on a more accelerated tempo. Obviously this is what is absent at present. To me, consensus in leadership is fundamental to the success of Big State policy on a global scale.
Thank you, Bill.
I agree we need to address climate change and we need public investment to sustain the economy. We knew it for long time and we have been spending lots of public money. The problem is how long it can last. If someone looks at the Japanese government, he or she may think it is a good example of how long it can last far beyond what ordinary citizens would think sustainable. I think it’s just fortunate, not sustainable. I’m sorry that I come to a same conclusion as yours. The next question is what will happen after the Big State era. Climate change will force us to compromise our lifestyles more than we can imagine today and the West will be more vulnerable to the aggression. I’m afraid that’s a mega trend we have to sustain until innovation, evolution or revolution is made by us or a third party.
Best,
Norio